p> * If the euro emerges, as I believe it will, as a strong and stable currency, it will provide the countries in the region with an important reference currency, an anchor towards which, should the intention arise, monetary policy could credibly be oriented. * Furthermore, EMU is set to bring about the development of a truly unified European financial market, close to that of the United States in depth and sophistication. The competitive pressures of this euro area financial market will create more favourable financing conditions for borrowers. A number of central and eastern European countries have already successfully tapped this market. In view of these effects, it is altogether natural that the ECB has
started to follow with great interest economic and financial developments
in the wider Europe, particularly in those countries which have applied for
EU membership. Moreover, the ECB monitors closely the exchange rate
developments with those countries which have established some form of
exchange rate link to the euro. The euro has the potential to become more than just a new currency
for almost 300 million people in 11 countries. It may also become a
unifying symbol, standing for all that the peoples of Europe have in
common. Consequently, the public perception of the euro could endow the
single currency with a role in the European integration process reaching
beyond monetary policy in the strict sense. May the euro contribute to the
establishment of what the preamble to the Treaty Establishing the European
Community calls: "an ever closer union among the peoples of Europe". *** The single European monetary policy Speech by Willem F. Duisenberg President of the European Central Bank at the University of Hohenheim on 9 February 1999, in Hohenheim, Germany Ladies and gentlemen, The single European monetary policy has been a
reality for a little more than five weeks. After years of intensive
preparatory work and successful economic convergence, monetary policy is
now jointly determined for a large part of Europe by the Governing Council
of the European Central Bank. The monetary policy is implemented by the
Eurosystem, the name given to the ECB and the 11 central banks of the EU
Member States participating in Monetary Union. The single currency is quoted on the international financial markets
and is used in non-cash payments. However, the euro will not appear as yet
in tangible form as banknotes and coins. Nonetheless there is no doubt that
this currency, which was only brought into existence on 1 January 1999,
will play an important role both within the euro area and beyond. There is good reason for this confidence, ladies and gentlemen.
Overall the first few weeks went smoothly for the single currency and the
monetary policy of the Eurosystem. The start did not pass by entirely
without a hitch - which was not to be expected in any case, given the
significance and scale of this project - but there were no major
complications. Monetary Union is a unique and outstanding achievement. It provides
the great opportunity to achieve the goal of lasting price stability
throughout Europe. Price stability is the best contribution that monetary
policy can make to lasting economic and employment growth in Europe. The
national governments and all those involved in collective wage bargaining
are being called on to remove the structural causes of the excessively high
unemployment. We can only hope that the introduction of the euro will spur
the implementation of structural reforms. The stability-oriented monetary policy strategy of the Eurosystem The Treaty establishing the European Community assigns the European
System of Central Banks (ESCB) - and thereby the Eurosystem - the primary
objective of maintaining price stability. The Governing Council will do its
utmost to fulfil this task and to explain its monetary policy so as to be
comprehensible to the general public. For this reason we have developed a
stability-oriented monetary policy which essentially consists of three main
elements. The Governing Council has published a quantitative definition of its
primary objective, price stability. This gives clear guidance for
expectations in relation to future price developments. Price stability is
defined as an increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices of the
euro area of less than 2% compared with the previous year. The publication
of this definition provides the public and the European Parliament with a
clear benchmark against which to measure the success of the single monetary
policy, and thereby provides for the transparency and accountability of the
Eurosystem and its policy. The wording "less than 2%" clearly defines the upper limit for the
measured inflation rate which is compatible with price stability. I do not
think I need emphasise that deflation - or a sustained fall in prices -
would be incompatible with price stability. The latest available data for
the annual rate of inflation according to the Harmonised Index of Consumer
Prices for the euro area as a whole fall within the definition of price
stability. This outcome is clearly the result, above all, of the successful
monetary policy of the national central banks in the years before the start
of Monetary Union. The ECB has only been responsible for monetary policy for a little
more than one month. It will only be possible to judge the success of its
current policy in one to two years'time. This reflects the fact that the
transmission of monetary policy impulses is subject to relatively long and
variable time lags. The Governing Council has therefore emphasised that
price stability must be maintained in the medium term. This statement
underlines not only the need for a forward-looking approach to monetary
policy, but also takes into consideration the short-term volatility of
prices in response to non-monetary shocks which are beyond the control of
monetary policy. In order to achieve the goal of price stability, our strategy rests,
in particular, on two "pillars". Before I explain this in more detail, I
should like to emphasise that traditional and previously established
macroeconomic relationships could change as a consequence of the
introduction of the euro. This was one key reason why neither a monetary
targeting nor a direct inflation targeting strategy could be applied. Our
strategy is also more than just a simple combination of these two
approaches. Rather, it is precisely tailored to the needs of the ECB. The first pillar of the monetary policy strategy is a prominent role
for money. Since inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon in the
medium term, the money supply provides a natural "nominal anchor" for a
monetary policy geared to safe-guarding price stability. To emphasise this
prominent role, the Governing Council has published a quantitative
reference value for growth in the money supply. The first reference value
decided upon by the Governing Council for growth in M3 was 4.5% per annum
and was published on 1 December. This value is based on the above-mentioned
definition of price stability and assumes a trend growth in real gross
domestic product of 2-2.5% per annum, as well as a medium-term reduction in
the velocity of circulation of M3 of around 0.5-1% per annum. We shall not, however, respond mechanistically to deviations from the
reference value for money supply growth, but shall first analyse them
carefully for signals relating to future price developments. Larger or
sustained deviations normally signal risks to price stability. The second pillar of the monetary policy strategy consists in a
broadly based assessment of the outlook for price developments in the
entire euro area. This assessment will be based on a broad range of
monetary policy indicators. In particular, those variables which could
contain information on future price developments will be analysed in depth.
This analysis should not only provide information on the risks for price
development, but should also help to identify the causes of unexpected
changes in important economic variables. Some commentators reduced this comprehensive analysis to an inflation
forecast. At the same time, there were demands for the ECB to have to
publish these forecasts in order to satisfy the need for transparency and
accountability. Therefore allow me to make this clear: our strategy
includes a comprehensive analysis of numerous indicators and several
forecasts. To focus on a single official inflation forecast of the
Eurosystem for a specific point in time would in no way accurately reflect
our internal analytical and decision-making process. It would impinge upon
the transparency and clarity of the explanation of our policy. The
publication of an official inflation forecast would also be inappropriate
with regard to the accountability of the ECB, all the more so if this
forecast were based on the assumption of no change in the monetary policy.
The success of the monetary policy of the ECB should primarily be measured
in terms of the maintenance of price stability, not the accuracy of its
conditional forecasts. The stability-oriented monetary policy strategy of the Eurosystem,
which I have just outlined, constitutes a new and clear strategy. It
emphasises the primacy of the goal of price stability. It takes into
account the inevitable uncertainties concerning economic relationships
inherent in the transition to Monetary Union and the associated systemic
changes and guarantees a high degree of transparency. Ladies and gentlemen, allow me to comment on certain suggestions on
the orientation of monetary policy which have recently appeared in the
press. Some of these ideas give the impression that monetary policy should
concentrate upon objectives other than price stability, since stable prices
have already been achieved. Inter alia, it has been suggested that the ECB
should react more or less mechanistically to exchange rate developments or
other variables such as, for instance, unit labour costs. Furthermore,
there were calls for monetary policy, by means of reductions in interest
rates, to be used to combat unemployment. Against this background there is
a need to set out clearly the possibilities and limitations of monetary
policy. Both the reasoning in the Maastricht Treaty and many economic
analyses show that the best contribution the single monetary policy can
make to employment growth is to concentrate on price stability. Without
such a clear approach there is a danger that the public may question the
commitment of the Eurosystem to the goal of maintaining price stability.
Inflation expectations, risk premia and thus long-term rates would rise.
This would increase the cost of the investment which is necessary for a
sustained and lasting rise in the standard of living. Even under the best possible circumstances, though - i.e. if it
proves to be possible to assure lasting price stability - monetary policy
alone cannot solve the major economic problems of unemployment and future
problems in social security systems. The Governing Council regards the current high level of unemployment
in the euro area as a matter of great concern. This problem is, however,
predominantly a structural one. It is mainly the result of the rigidities
in the labour and goods markets in the euro area which have arisen partly
through an excessive and disproportionate degree of regulation. Structural
economic reforms, which target the reduction of rigidities, are the
appropriate solution. In those euro area countries in which such reforms
have been implemented unemployment figures have declined markedly. In
addition, I should like to emphasise that moderate wage developments and a
reduction in the burden of tax and social security contributions would
generally help to reduce unemployment. This would be the case even if the
country concerned did not trade heavily with its neighbouring countries.
The positive influence of low taxes and wages on employment clearly has
overall benefits from an international perspective. Such a policy should
not be denounced as "wage dumping". Turning to the role of exchange rates between the euro and other
important currencies outside the EU, in particular the US dollar, the
Eurosystem has, in formulating its monetary policy strategy, made an
unambiguous choice. This strategy clearly rules out explicit or implicit
objectives or target zones for the euro exchange rate. The pursuit of an
exchange rate objective could easily jeopardise the maintenance of the
objective of price stability and could thereby also be detrimental to real
economic development. Target zones for exchange rates could, for example,
lead to the ECB having to raise interest rates in a recession, despite
increasing downward pressure on prices. I am sure you will agree that such
a mechanistic response to a change in the euro exchange rate would not be
optimal. Furthermore, it is important to remember that we are living in a
world with high capital mobility. Exchange rate agreements, which might
have been possible to implement until recently, are no longer feasible. The lack of an exchange rate target does not mean that the ECB is
totally indifferent to or takes no account of the euro exchange rate. On
the contrary, the exchange rate will be observed and analysed as a
potentially important monetary policy indicator in the context of the
broadly based assessment of the outlook for price developments. A stability-
oriented monetary and fiscal policy, as stipulated by the Maastricht Treaty
and the Stability and Growth Pact, is an essential pre-condition for a
stable euro exchange rate. Of course, there is no guarantee of lasting
exchange rate stability, not even in a fixed exchange rate regime. Exchange
rate fluctuations are often caused by structural or fiscal policy,
asymmetric real shocks or conjunctural differences. Monetary policy would
clearly be overburdened if it had to prevent such movements in the exchange
rate. We cannot and shall not gear our monetary policy towards a single
variable, whether a money supply aggregate, an index, the exchange rate or
an inflation forecast for a particular point in time. Nor can we be
involved in any ex ante co-ordination which would entail an obligation to
react to particular commitments or plans. The ECB will always carefully
analyse all relevant indicators. In this context, it is particularly
important that the economic causes of potential risks to price stability in
the euro area are understood as fully as possible. Appropriate monetary
policy decisions also depend upon the causes of unexpected changes in
important economic variables. The Governing Council must, for example, take
a view on whether changes in important indicators are of a temporary or
permanent nature, and whether a demand or supply shock is involved. In our
deliberations we also attempt to take into account how the financial
markets, consumers and firms are expected to react to monetary policy
decisions. I believe few would contest that such a complex analysis cannot
meaningfully be reduced to a more or less mechanistic reaction to a few
variables or a single official forecast. In addition, concern was often expressed that the Eurosystem would
not act transparently enough. In this context, it was said that a
transparent monetary policy also necessitated the publication of the
minutes of the meetings of the Governing Council and disclosure of the
voting behaviour of the individual members of the Council. For sound reasons the Governing Council decided not to adopt this
approach. The publication of individual positions could easily lead to
national influence being exerted over the individual Council members. The
members of the Governing Council must not, however, be seen as national
representatives. They decide together on the monetary policy for the euro
area as a whole. The Governing Council has committed itself to go beyond
the reporting and explanatory requirements laid down in the Treaty, which
are among the most comprehensive requirements by international standards. On the basis of our strategy, after every first meeting in the month
I deliver to the press a detailed explanation of our assessment of the
overall economic situation and, in particular, the outlook for price
stability. The content of this so-called "introductory statement" is very
close to what other central banks refer to as minutes. In this way, the
public receives comprehensive information immediately following the
meetings of the Governing Council. In addition, each month we shall publish
a detailed report on the economic situation and monetary policy throughout
the euro area in our Bulletin. Such rapid information on the results of the
meetings of the Governing Council and the current economic analysis of the
ECB without doubt demonstrates a high degree of openness and transparency.
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20, 21
|