p> The 1970s was a difficult decade for many countries, especially those
that rely on imported oil. The Polish strategy in the 1970s and later was
to stimulate the domestic economy through the importation of foreign
technology. This was not an unreasonable strategy in theory, but Western
economies were themselves in the midst of the energy crisis and the
recession it caused. Poland's effort to expand exports failed, hard-
currency debt accumulated, and the projected impact of Western technology
on the Polish economy was minimal. As the 1970s came to an end, it was
evident that domestic retrenchment would be essential — a difficult path in
light of the continuing unrest among Polish workers. The 1980s began with
roughly three years of martial law and an attempt to achieve economic
stabilization. After half-hearted economic reforms in the early 1980s, the rise of
Solidarity (which had been outlawed in 1982) proved that major systemic and
structural reform was necessary. Even so, and despite the fact that Polish
economic performance was deteriorating badly, serious economic reform did
not begin until the late 1980s. 3) The Polish Transition: The "Big Bang" in Practice The Polish transition from plan to market has been watched closely by
a variety of interested observers. Although many of the policy and systemic
changes introduced in Poland are familiar hallmarks of the general reform
scene, the speed of implementation in the Polish case is unique. There had been attempts to decentralize decision making in large state-
owned Polish enterprises in the 1980s, but these reforms failed to change
outcomes (a possible exception is their contribution to the wage explosion
that took place toward the end of the decade). Moreover, on the eve of
reform in Poland (the reform program began officially on January 1, 1990),
macroeco-nomic conditions there were in a state of severe disequilibrium.
Although the exact nature of monetary overhang in Poland (as elsewhere) has
been the subject of debate, there was a significant budget deficit, wage
increases were out of control, and hyperinflation had resulted. Poland's
hard-currency debt position was better than that of Hungary, but the debt
that had been accumulated did little to stimulate the Polish economy, the
zioty was overvalued, and no debt relief from external sources was in
sight. In the fall of 1989, most price controls were lifted (on both producer
and consumer goods), public spending was reduced, and the zioty was
devalued. In the second stage of major reform, begun in 1990, the budget
deficit was sharply cut, largely through a reduction of subsidies to state
enterprises. A positive real rate of interest was to be implemented, and
the market was to be used to signal changes in the value of the zloty. The
latter was a critical measure, because foreign trade and the impact of this
trade on the Polish industrial structure was to be a key component of the
overall reform strategy. In January of 1990, the government set the
exchange rate of the zloty at 9500 to the dollar (this represented a
devaluation from 1989), a rate roughly approximating its value on the black
market, and it established convertibility of the zloty for international
trade. Many trade restrictions were eliminated, and internal exchanges were
set up to handle the buying and selling of hard currencies. Although these
changes resulted in domestic inflation, the initial increases proved to be
short-term and the exchange rate of the zloty has proved to be realistic. Finally, wage increases were to be controlled partly through wage
indexation and partly through a new tax on wage increases that exceeded
established guidelines. Privatization is a major element of the Polish strategy of transition.
In 1990 the Polish government passed a law creating a Ministry of Ownership
Change, a mechanism to supervise the process of privatization.
Privatization has proceeded rapidly, though it has been achieved mainly for
small enterprises in the trade and service sectors. Industrial output in
the private sector grew by 8.5 percent in 1990 and is reported to represent
roughly 17 percent of total Polish industrial output
Though privatization has been very successful for small-scale enterprises,
the picture for large state enterprises is quite different. For reasons we
noted earlier, privatization of these enterprises has proceeded very
slowly. In addition, the economic position of these enterprises worsened as
the state took decisive measures to introduce a hard-budget constraint. In
addition to price changes and wage limitations, subsidies have been ended
and protection from foreign competition has been sharply reduced. This new
setting has encouraged enterprise managers to reduce costs by restricting
unnecessary output and reducing the labor force. However, the strong
commitment to rapid privatization was reinforced in June of 1991, when it
was announced that a major portion of state industry would be privatized
through creation of stock funds, with the population receiving vouchers. Beyond these changes in the state sector, new guidelines have been
introduced to monitor enterprise performance. Furthermore, a new Industrial
Restructuring Agency will consider how remaining state enterprises should
be handled, to what extent privatization is possible, and what
restructuring should take place for those enterprises that are not viable
in the new setting. These new arrangements are designed to ensure a rapid
transformation of the Polish industrial structure, to make it similar to
and competitive with market economic systems, and to achieve this result
quickly and as openly as possible. Note that these comprehensive reforms in Poland cover all the critical
areas discussed in Chapter 4 and earlier in this chapter. Moreover,
beginning from very precarious economic circumstance in 1989, these changes
were introduced simultaneously and rapidly. We will now do our best to
assess the early results. 4) The Polish Economy in the 1990s It is clear that economic reform in Poland has been radical and has
moved sharply and swiftly away from the plan toward the market. In addition
to the expanded influence of market mechanisms, decision making has been
decentralized, private property introduced, and incentive arrangements
changed. By most standards, the initial results have been encouraging. First, stabilization measures cut the rate of inflation sharply from a
reported 40-50 percent per month at the end of 1989 to roughly 4-5 percent
per month in 1990. At the same time output fell, though supplies of
consumer goods in stores increased. Employment in industry declined by 20
percent during 1989 and 1990, although it is reported that only a
relatively small portion of this reduction in the labor force was caused by
forced layoffs. The unemployment rate was reported to be 6.5 percent at the
end of 1990. Another major positive facet of the Polish reform experience has been
the foreign trade sector. There has been a significant expansion of
exports, especially to hard-currency markets. This expansion resulted in
part from the devaluation of the zloty to market-clearing levels and in
part from the reorientation of trade away from the Soviet Union and other
East European trading partners. At the same time, as a result of
restrictive policy measures and the higher domestic cost of these imports,
import demand declined. A third qualified success has been privatization. Although the initial
pace of privatization was rapid, this early privatization was largely that
of small-scale enterprises in the area of trade and services. Although
Polish reformers take seriously the need to pursue privatization of major
state enterprises, bringing this about will remain a critical task for the
next several years. Can these achievements be sustained in the coming years? We discuss
this issue more generally in the next section, but the Polish case deserves
specific comment. Quite clearly, the continued success of the Polish
transition will depend on the continuing implementation of appropriate
stabilization measures. Although this may seem relatively straightforward,
it requires cohesion and commitment among policy makers and willingness
among the populace to pay the costs of the transition. Pressures for wage
increases must be resisted, and the process of privatization must proceed.
To the extent that the latter can be achieved, the contours of new market
arrangements can be defined. Finally, although uncertainty in foreign
markets remains, relief of hard-currency debt will unquestionably add a
measure of flexibility. Another issue is the extent to which the Polish "success" (if we can
call it that) was promoted by Western assistance. In light of the Polish
leadership's commitment to rapid transition, the West has provided
considerable assistance in the form of exchange-rate stabilization funds,
debt restructuring, and government guarantees. HUNGARY: THE NEW ECONOMIC MECHANISM AND PRIVATIZATION Early works in comparative economic systems devoted little attention
to the Hungarian economy. Over the last twenty years, however. Western
economists have begun to pay more attention to Hungary. As one prominent observer of Hungary and other East European systems
has noted, "The Hungarian reform experience says as much about central
planning as it does about Hungary, and therefore an understanding of that
experience is important for those interested in the prospects for reform in
all of Eastern Europe, and indeed, in the Soviet Union. In other words,
Hungary is a prototype of economic reform for the former planned socialist
economic systems of Eastern Europe, and presumably elsewhere. These
thoughts, expressed some ten years ago, remain relevant in the 1990s as
Hungary, like other socialist systems, pursues a transition to the market.
However, the background of reform in Hungary is important to a proper
analysis of contemporary problems and prospects. Prior to 1968, Hungary applied the Soviet model of centrally planned
socialism in a typical fashion. But then, in 1968, Hungary began to
introduce by far the most radical economic reform attempted in Eastern
Europe (with the exception of Yugoslavia). In the words of one early
observer of this reform, it clearly represents the most radical postwar
change, in the economic system of any Comecon country, which has been
maintained over a period of years and gives promise of continuity. Although the reform program in Hungary met with only partial success,
the problems that have arisen (conflicts of objectives, for example, and
difficulty in persuading participants to change their ways) are fundamental
to the reform experience of planned socialist systems. Hungary shares many features with other Eastern and Southeastern
European countries, such as Yugoslavia. It provides a refreshing contrast
to the Soviet Union, which in some important respects is atypical. Hungary
is a small country heavily dependent on foreign trade. The Hungarian
experience with reforming foreign trade, and in particular its efforts to
become integrated into the world economy both East and West, is
prototypical. The difficulties of reforming the foreign trade mechanism arc
crucial to the Hungarian economy as well as to the economies of many other
systems of Eastern Europe. 1) Hungary: The Setting Hungary is located in central Europe. Its land area of approximately
36,000 square miles makes it roughly the same size as the state of Indiana.
Its population of about 11 million is comparable to that of the population
of Illinois. Although Hungary is not self-sufficient in energy, it docs
have supplies of coat, oil, and a number of minerals, including important
bauxite deposits. Although it has some rolling hills and low mountains, Hungary is
basically a flat country with good agricultural land and a favorable
climate. As in other East European countries, the period since World War II
has seen the population flow from rural to urban areas and a changing
balance of industrial and agricultural activity. Today, approximately half
the population lives in urban areas. Hungary is not particularly prosperous. Most estimates of its gross
national product or per capita gross national product place Hungary in the
middle of the East European countries. It is generally wealthier than
Bulgaria and Yugoslavia and certainly wealthier than Albania; it ranks
behind East Germany and Czechoslovakia. Hungary's per capita income appears
to be close to that of Greece. In this sense, economic development remains
a key issue in Hungary. By the standards of Western Europe, Hungary remains
relatively poor; by the standards of the Third World, Hungary ranks among
the more affluent countries. 2) The Hungarian Economy: Prereform The postwar reconstruction of the Hungarian economy began quite
modestly in 1945. Before the implementation of a three-year plan in 1947
(1947-1949), the main policies included stabilization of the currency,
changes in the nature of rural landholdings, and the beginnings of
nationalization. The first three-year plan was designed primarily to bring
the economy up to prewar levels of economic activity. During this time, a planning mechanism was created and the
share of national income going to investment increased sharply. The changes
were not radical, however, and balanced development was envisioned. The era of balanced development came to an end with the introduction
of a five-year plan in 1950. The share of national income devoted to
investment was increased substantially, and the bulk of new investment was
directed toward heavy industry. This policy was partially reversed toward
the end of the plan period, but it was reaffirmed in 1955-1956. A number of economic trouble spots cried out for attention. There was
an observed need to improve industrial labor productivity, especially
through the development of a better incentive system to offset the
declining supply of labor from rural areas. Supply-demand imbalances were
growing increasingly severe. Waste and imbalance in the material-technical
supply system created the need for a substantially modified coordinating
mechanism among enterprises. In addition, excess demand for investment led to substantial amounts
of unfinished new construction and to the neglect of old facilities. Some
mechanisms for the more rational allocation of capital investment had to be
found. The adoption and diffusion of technological advances were seen as
inadequate. Technological improvement was considered crucial for continued
development of the economy. This background seems familiar: a small country, the Soviet
(Stalinist) model of industrialization, overcentralization, emphasis on
extensive growth, rigidities of the plan mechanism, incentive problems, and
the resulting difficulties. Against this background, the New Economic
Mechanism first promulgated in a party resolution in 1966 was put into,
practice in 1968. Over twenty years later, it remains one of the most
important reform programs of planned socialist systems. 3) Intent of the New Economic Mechanism There is disagreement about the importance and effect of the Hungarian
reform program. The New Economic Mechanism (NEM) has generally been
interpreted as leaving the power to control the main lines of economic
activity (volume and direction of investment, consumption shares) with the
central authorities, while relying on the market to execute the routine
activities of the system. The NEM called for substantial decentralization
of decision-making authority and responsibility from upper-level
administrative agencies to the enterprise level. In a general way, NEM
bears a close resemblance to the Lange model. Let us consider the original
blueprint of NEM. The objective of NEM was to combine the central manipulation of key
variables with local responsibility for the remaining decisions. The first
change was a significant reduction in the number and complexity of the
directives firms; for large state-owned firms, the traditional problems
remain. Valuation is difficult, especially in loss-making enterprises.
Moreover, it is hard to find buyers for these types of enterprises, let
alone to arbitrate the potential rights of past owners. And just as
elsewhere, privatization in Hungary is likely to become slower and more
difficult as the focus shifts to the less attractive, large enterprises. In addition to privatization per se, Hungary has addressed the
creation of infrastructure (for example, a stock market) and new rules
designed to change the guidance of enterprises. Accounting procedures have
been refined and bankruptcy laws strengthened so that state subsidies can
be curtailed and hard budgets introduced into large state-owned
enterprises.
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4
|