p> What special provisions will be in place that affect the relationship
between the privatized entity and other firms, including established and
new competitors, firms that are up and down stream in the distribution
chain, etc.? In the discussion that follows, the focus will be on
bargaining problems of the latter kind. One presumes that, because of the
complexity and diversity of the issues during the transition, the state is
not in a position to resolve them by fiat rather, over the transition, the
state is presumed to be one negotiator among many. Bargaining problems of this kind can be resolved in a variety of ways.
At one extreme, an explicit institutional structure may be established by
the state to facilitate an orderly negotiation of the issues. This
institution would specify: a) the interests that should be represented in the bargaining process; b) the space of issues over which these interests can negotiate; c) what degree of consensus is sufficient to conclude negotiations; d) who will represent "the state" the founding ministry are some agency established specially to deal with privatization; e) what will happen if negotiations break down? At the other extreme the state may provide no procedural guidelines
whatever as to how the issues should be resolved in this procedural vacuum,
the economic rights in question may simply be expropriated by whichever
party - typically the current management - is strategically located to do
so. Relative to the general trend that appears to be emerging in Central
and Eastern Europe, there should be made opportunities for decentralized
negotiation. Our process-oriented perspective does suggest an indirect, "hand off"
way to exercise some control over this phase of the process, the government
can introduce some checks and balances into the negotiations. For example,
of the three "primary" parties at the bargaining table-management,
employees of the enterprise, and the state agency responsible for
privatization - the first two parties have every incentive to design
privatization plans that inhibit competitive pressures, while the third
will inevitably be more concerned this effecting a successful sale of the
enterprise than with issues such as the competitiveness of the resulting
market structure. From the standpoint of the public interest then the
outcome of multilateral bargaining is bound to be sub-optimal, provided
that participation in the process is restricted to the three primary
parties. Moreover, the directions in which these outcomes will deviate from
the optimal are more or less predictable. The Multilateral Bargaining model provides a useful analytical tool
for investigating the effectiveness of this approach to policy making. In other contexts, the multilateral Bargaining model has been used
descriptively to explain how during the process of multilateral
negotiation, coalitions are formed, deals are struck, and compromises are
reached. 5) Political economy. A second basic premise is that any policy recommendations must be
both economically and politically consistent. This consistency requires a
specification of the relationship between short-term economic developments
and longer-term political ramifications. Obviously, economic policy
objectives cannot be pursued in isolation, since the prevailing political
configuration will constrain the set of options available to planners of
the transition process. On the other hand, economic post-privatization
economy develops, new interests will acquire economic power and new
institutions will emerge to strengthen the power of groups that wish to
defend these institutions. The dynamic interaction between these economic
and political facets of massive privatization programs must be taken into
account. Indeed, one can expect that models, which ignore political
economic feedback effects, will have a natural tendency to overestimate the
prospects for a successful transition. The following example illustrates the kind of political-economic
interaction that could adversely affect the reform process. Policy makers
in Central and Eastern Europe appear to be overly complacent in their
reliance of foreign competition as the main disciplinary device that will
force monopolists to operate efficiently. Indeed, Polish officials cite
their country’s liberal tradition in the area of trade policy when
questioned about the viability of this approach to antimonopoly policy. Our
dynamic political-economic perspective leads to skepticism about this heavy
dependence on competition from abroad. If a seems very likely, the post-privatization industrial structure
turns out to be highly over-concentrated and inefficient, then the main
effect of threatening foreign competition will be to unleash a powerful
confluence of political forces in favor of protectionism. Owners of the
domestic enterprises will lobby to defend their rents, managers will lobby
to defend privileges, and workers will lobby to defend their jobs. Because
the problem of unemployment never really arose under communism, the potent
tension between introducing free trade and maintaining employment levels
never became apparent. 2.2. Poland and Hungary as the best example of transition in the East Europe Economic Reform in Eastern Europe: The Background The background of economic reform in Eastern Europe is not unlike that
in the Soviet Union, even though, as I have emphasized, the setting is
rather different. The brief political thaw following the death of Stalin in
the early 1950s did permit a freer discussion of ideas, which, along with
growing problems of economic performance, led to limited attempts to
develop and implement economic reform. Initially, these changes were modest
in scope, and they typically followed the Soviet reform pattern: Try to
improve decision making while preserving socialist objectives and the
essence of the planning system. This was the focus of the New Economic
System in the GDR and of the New Economic Mechanism introduced in Hungary
in 1968. The potential for genuine economic reform was certainly limited by
Soviet influence. Indeed in some cases (such as Czechoslovakia in 1968),
reform was abruptly forestalled by Soviet intervention. In other cases,
such as Hungary, reform attempts dating from the late 1960s were sustained
on a limited basis, to become the background for more serious reform in the
present era. There were, then, numerous attempts at reform in Eastern
Europe. What were the major forces promoting these efforts? First, as was the case in the Soviet Union, rates of economic growth
in Eastern Europe have undergone a long-term secular decline. The magnitude
of this decline (see Table 1) has varied from case to case, but overall it
has been pervasive. Moreover, these countries had taken pride in being high-
growth economies, even if the costs, such as little growth of consumer well-
being, were also high. At the same time, growth in productivity slackened,
especially in the late 1970s and 1980s. And inflation quickened, though it
was most serious in Poland and Yugoslavia. Repressed inflation, though
difficult to measure, grew in importance in the 1980s. Second, East European countries relied heavily on foreign trade as a
means of stimulating economic growth in the 1970s. Their strategy was to
promote exports in Western markets so that the imports required both to
stimulate technological change in industry and to enhance consumer well-
being could be obtained without the growth of hard-currency debt.
Unfortunately, this strategy was not successful. The energy crisis led to a
significant slackening of Western markets at the very time when East
European nations were becoming more aggressive in these markets. East
European imports were sustained, but largely by means of building a
substantial hard-currency debt. The magnitude of debt repayment
subsequently led to considerable internal belt-tightening for these
countries in the 1980s — precisely the opposite of what had been intended. Third, one could argue that in Eastern Europe, the possibilities for
economic growth through extensive means had initially been less promising
than in the Soviet case and had been exhausted more quickly. In light of
the level of economic development in Eastern Europe compared to that in the
Soviet Union, it is not surprising that the imperative for reform was
strong and that developments of the Gorbachev era quickly spilled over into
Eastern Europe. In the absence of Soviet backing, interest in the
administrative command model faded fast. Table 1. Economic Growth and Performance in Eastern Europe: The Background to Reform | |1961-70 |1971-80 |1981-85 |1985 |1986 |
|Eastern |3.4 |2.4 |1.0 |.2 |2.2 |
|Europe | | | | | |
|Bulgaria|5.0 |2.3 |.1 |-3.2 |4.7 |
|Czechosl|2.4 |2.3 |1.0 |.4 |1.9 |
|ovakia | | | | | |
|East |3.2 |3.5 |1.7 |3.3 |1.6 |
|Germany | | | | | |
|Hungary |3.1 |2.5 |.6 |-2.3 |2.4 |
|Poland |3.3 |3.0 |1.0 |.2 |2.1 |
|Romania |4.2 |3.5 |-.6 |-1.4 |3.1 | East European Reform Programs: Similarities and Differences In this chapter we pay special attention to Poland and Hungary. We do
so because these countries are both examples of aggressive reform but have
employed different strategies. However, before we consider these cases in
greater detail, it is useful to summarize the East European reform
experience, noting important similarities and differences among the various
cases. To do so will entail some repetition of basic themes. First, economic reform in Eastern Europe (at least in Poland, Hungary,
and Czechoslovakia) is generally described as a transition in that these
countries seek to replace the planned economy with a market economy rather
than attempting merely to modify the former. Second, transition programs have varied in speed and intensity. Some
countries have pursued reform on a "gradual" basis, whereas others, like
Poland, have pursued what is often termed a "big bang," or rapid, approach
to reform. However, we must remember that even in those countries not
pursuing a "big bang" or "shock therapy" approach, the process of
transition in Eastern Europe has been relatively rapid, especially when
compared to reforms of the past - and notably so when compared to the
recent Soviet record. It is important, therefore, to be aware of the basic
issues associated with transition and of the extent to which the attempted
speed of transition alters the overall reform experience. Third, although it is possible to examine and understand the basic
elements of economic reform and even of transition from one system to
another, we really do not have a general theory of change in economic
systems. In some cases — for example, during such a period of rapid change
as the 1990s — it is difficult even to develop a way to classify the issues
involved in transition. Fourth, important differences exist from one country to another. Our
view of the socialist transition process is heavily influenced by our image
of the best-known and most advanced reforms, such as those of Poland,
Hungary, and Czechoslovakia. We know much less about, and tend to pay less
attention to developments where reforms are proceeding at a slower pace, as
in Romania and Bulgaria. Figure 1 offers a simple, stylized view of
contemporary political and economic reform (transition) in Eastern Europe. Figure 1. Reform in Eastern Europe POLAND: FROM PLAN TO MARKET VIA SHOCK THERAPY Until Solidarity won the parliamentary elections in Poland in the
summer of 1989, the Polish economy had been, since the end of World War II,
a rather typical planned socialist economic system. State ownership
predominated, and though economic reform was attempted in varying degrees
at different times, little real systemic change had taken place. Moreover,
as Table 1 shows, the rate of economic growth continued to decline, and the
period saw recurring shortages, increasing inflation, and an understandably
declining work ethic. Beginning in 1990, Poland took decisive steps toward a market economy.
This "shock therapy" approach was to be sudden, and in this it differed
significantly from the gradualist approach being discussed in other
socialist systems. In addition to treeing prices, Poland implemented
monetary controls, the zloty was made convertible into hard currencies, and
steps were taken to control wage increases. As we shall see, the "shock therapy" approach has not been without
critics. Moreover, although the Polish case quickly attracted the interest
of those who study the problems of socialist transition, it was viewed as
unique. Thus it was argued that. for a variety of reasons that were
discussed earlier, reform was much more likely to succeed in Poland than in
a case like the Soviet Union. But before we examine the Polish reform
experience in greater detail, we must review what brought the Polish
economy to the reform phase and how, at that point, it might be different
from other socialist countries. I begin our discussion of Poland with a brief examination of the
setting. Then I discuss the Polish command system, considering the extent
to which this system led to distortions in the Polish economic structure.
Finally, I turn to the issue of transition and examine the mechanisms
utilized and the results achieved thus far. 1) Poland: The Setting By European standards, Poland is a relatively large country. With a
land area of just over 300,000 square kilometers, it is just over half the
size of France. Moreover, with a population that approached 38 million in
1990, Poland is some 68 percent of the size of France in terms of
population. Poland is frequently viewed as having a homogeneous society, a factor
that facilitates economic reform. Although social homogeneity is difficult
to measure and may well be overstated in the Polish case and in other cases
(for example, there are regional differentials, urban-rural differentials,
and the like), the basic statistical evidence is strong. In terms of
religion, 95 percent of the Polish population is Roman Catholic. From a
stannic standpoint, 98.7 percent of the population is Polish, and only a
few minority groups occur.
Urbanization and industrialization have changed the nature of Polish life
and customs, but the church, family, and folk ties that have sustained
Poland for a long time remain strong. Thus, although Poland must deal with
problems of modernization, it also has valued traditions and a clear
identity. These qualities make implementing change more manageable here
than in many other countries.
In terms of natural resources, Poland is a country of considerable regional
diversity, though major portions of the land area are not especially
fertile.
Poland's main energy resource is coal; basic minerals and some deposits of
oil and natural gas also exist. Both basic data and methods of computing
economic aggregates of socialist systems are currently under scrutiny. New
evidence that will make it possible to do different kinds of computations
may well lead to important adjustments. With these reservations in mind,
however, we note that Poland was reported to have a per capita gross
national product of approximately $4500 measured in 1989 U.S. dollars. This
figure places it between the high-income countries of the region (Hungary
and Czechoslovakia) and the low-income countries (Bulgaria, Romania,
Yugoslavia) and at one-quarter that of the United States. Prior to the
onset of major economic reform, the bulk of Polish industry was state-owned
and planned. Agriculture (representing roughly one-fifth of total Polish
output) was a mixed system wherein the private sector produced about three-
quarters of the total agricultural product. Foreign trade turnover — that
is, exports plus imports — represents roughly one-third of Polish product,
again using U.S. dollar measures. 2) Poland: The Command Economy The organizational arrangements of the Polish command economy were
established immediately after World War II and closely resembled those
prevailing in the Soviet Union. There was widespread nationalization of
property, central planning mechanisms were established, and agriculture was
socialized. In addition to organizational arrangements, Polish economic
policies of the era, such as those on investment, sectoral development, and
the like, closely mirrored the Soviet model. Although Poland attempted modification of the command system as early
as 1956 when collectivization was abandoned, little actually changed. Over
time, private agriculture was neglected by the state, and continuing
political protests, especially in the early 1970s, signaled both political
and economic difficulties.
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4
|