p>But the Federal Reserve System can go too far in expanding the money
supply. If the supply of money and credit grows much faster than the
production of goods and services in the economy, then prices will
increase, and the rate of inflation will rise. Inflation is a serious
problem for those who live on fixed incomes, since the income of those
individuals remains constant while the amount of goods and services they
can purchase with their income decreases. Inflation may also hurt banks
and other financial institutions that lend money, as well as savers. In a
period of unanticipated inflation, as the value of money decreases in
terms of what it will purchase, loans are repaid with dollars that are
worth less. The funds that people have saved are worth less, too.When banks and savers anticipate higher inflation, they will try to
protect themselves by demanding higher interest rates on loans and
savings accounts. This will be especially true on long-term loans and
savings deposits, if the higher inflation is considered likely to
continue for many years. But higher interest rates create problems for
borrowers and those who want to invest in capital goods. If the supply of money and credit grows too slowly, however, then
interest rates are again likely to rise, leading to decreased spending
for capital investments and consumer durable goods (products designed for
long-term use, such as television sets, refrigerators, and personal
computers). Such decreased spending will hurt many businesses and may
lead to a recession, an economic slowdown in which the national output of
goods and services falls. When that happens, wages and salaries paid to
individual workers will fall or grow more slowly, and some workers will
be laid off, facing possibly long periods of unemployment. For all of these reasons, bankers and other financial experts watch the
Federal Reserve’s actions with monetary policy very closely. There are
regular reports in the media about policy changes made by the Federal
Reserve System, and even about statements made by Federal Reserve
officials that may indicate that the Federal Reserve is going to change
the supply of money and interest rates. The chairman of the Federal
Reserve System is widely considered to be one of the most influential
people in the world because what the Federal Reserve does so dramatically
affects the U.S. and world economies, especially financial markets. LABOR AND LABOR MARKETS Labor includes work done for employers and work done in a person’s own
household, but labor markets deal only with work that is done for some
form of financial compensation. Labor markets include all the means by
which workers find jobs and by which employers locate workers to staff
their businesses. A number of factors influence labor and labor markets
in the United States, including immigration, discrimination, labor
unions, unemployment, and income inequality between the rich and poor. The official definition of the U.S. labor force includes people who are
at least 16 years old and either working, waiting to be recalled from a
layoff, or actively looking for work within the past 30 days. In 1998 the
U.S. labor force included nearly 138 million people, most of them working
in full-time or part-time jobs. Most people in the United States receive their income as wages and
salaries paid by firms that have hired individuals to work as their
employees. Those wages and salaries are the prices they receive for the
labor services they provide to their employers. Like other prices, wages
and salaries are determined primarily by market forces. Labor Supply and Demand The wages and salaries that U.S. workers earn vary from occupation to
occupation, across geographic regions, and according to workers’ levels
of education, training, experience, and skill. As with goods and services
purchased by consumers, labor is traded in markets that reflect both
supply and demand. In general, higher wages and salaries are paid in
occupations where labor is more scarce—that is, in jobs where the demand
for workers is relatively high and the supply of workers with the
qualifications and ability to do that work is relatively low. The demand
for workers in particular occupations depends largely on how much the
work they do adds to a firm’s revenues. In other words, workers who
create more products or higher-priced products will be worth more to
employers than workers who make fewer or less valuable products. The
supply of workers in any occupation is affected by the amount of time and
effort required to enter that occupation compared to other things workers
might do. Workers seeking higher wages often learn skills that will increase the
likelihood of finding a higher-paying job. The knowledge, skills, and
experience a worker has acquired are the worker’s human capital.
Education and training can clearly increase workers’ human capital and
productivity, which makes them more valuable to employers. In general,
more educated individuals make more money at their jobs. However, a
greater level of education does not always guarantee higher wages.
Certain professions that demand a high level of education, such as
teaching elementary and secondary school, are not high-paying. Such
situations arise when the number of people with the training to do that
job is relatively large compared with the number of people that employers
want to hire. Of course this situation can change over time if, for
example, fewer young people choose to train for the profession. Supply and demand factors change in labor markets, just as they do in
markets for goods and services. As a result, occupations that paid high
wages and salaries in the past sometimes become outdated, while entirely
new occupations are created as a result of technological change or
changes in the goods and services consumers demand. For example,
blacksmiths were once among the most skilled workers in the United
States; today, computer programmers and software developers are in great
demand. The process of creative destruction carries over from product markets to
labor markets because the demand for particular goods and services
creates a demand for the labor to produce them. Conversely, when the
demand for particular goods or services decreases, the demand for labor
to produce them will also fall. Similarly, when new technologies create
new products or new ways of producing existing products, some workers
will have new job opportunities, but other workers might have to retrain,
relocate, or take new jobs. Factors Affecting Labor Markets Changes in society and in the makeup of the population also affect labor
markets. For example, starting in the 1960s it became more common for
married women to work outside the home. Unprecedented numbers of
women—many with little previous job experience and training—entered the
labor markets for the first time during the 1970s. As a result, wages for
entry-level jobs were pushed down and did not rise as rapidly as they had
in the past. This decline in entry-level wages was further fueled by huge
numbers of teens who were also entering the labor market for the first
time. These young people were the children of the baby boom of 1946 to
1964, a period in which the birth rate increased dramatically in the
United States. So, two changes—one affecting women’s roles in the labor
market, the other in the makeup of the age of the workforce—combined to
affect the labor market. The baby boomers’ effects have continued to reverberate through the U.S.
economy. For example, starting salaries for people with college degrees
became depressed when large numbers of baby boomers started graduating
from college. And as workers born during the boom have aged, the work
force in the United States has grown progressively older, with the
percentage of workers under the age of 25 falling from 20.3 percent in
1980 to 14.3 percent in 1997. By the 1990s, the women and baby boomers who first entered the job market
in the 1970s had acquired more experience and training. Therefore, the
aging of the labor force was not affecting entry-level jobs as it once
did, and starting salaries for college graduates were rising rapidly
again. There will be, however, other kinds of labor market and public
policy issues to face when the baby boomers begin to retire in the early
decades of the 21st century. Immigration Labor markets in the United States have also been significantly affected
by the immigration of families and workers from other nations. Most
families and workers in the United States can trace their heritage to
immigrants. In fact, before the 20th century, while the United States was
trying to settle its frontiers, it allowed essentially unlimited
immigration. see Immigration: A Nation of Immigrants. In these periods
the U.S. economy had more land and other natural resources than it was
able to use, because labor was so scarce. Immigration served as one of
the main remedies for this shortage of labor. Generally, immigration raises national output and income levels. These
changes occur because immigration increases the number of workers in the
economy, which allows employers to produce more goods and services.
Capital resources in the economy may also become more valuable as
immigration increases. The number of workers available to work with
machines and tools increases, as does the number of consumers who want to
buy goods and services. However, wages for jobs that are filled by large
numbers of immigrants may decrease. This wage decline stems from greater
competition for these jobs and from the fact that many immigrants are
willing to work for lower wages than other U.S. workers. Immigration into the United States is now regulated by a system of quotas
that limits the number of immigrants who can legally enter the country
each year. In 1964 Congress changed immigration policies to give
preference to those with families already in the United States, to
refugees facing political persecution, and to individuals with other
humanitarian concerns. Before that time, more weight had been placed on
immigrants’ labor-market skills. Although this change in policy helped
reunite families, it also increased the supply of unskilled labor in the
nation, especially in the states of California, Florida, and New York. In
1990 Congress modified the immigration legislation to set a separate
annual quota for immigrants with job skills needed in the United States.
But people with family members who are already U.S. citizens remain the
largest category of immigrants, and U.S. immigration law still puts less
focus on job skills than do immigration laws in many other market
economies, including Canada and many of the nations of Western Europe. Discrimination Women and many minorities have long faced discrimination in U.S. labor
markets. Employed women earn less, on average, than men with similar
levels of education. In part this wage disparity reflects different
educational choices that women and men have made. In the past, women have
been less likely to study engineering, sciences, and other technical
fields that generally pay more. In part, the wage differences result from
women leaving the job market for a period of years to raise children.
Another reason for the disparity in wages between men and women is that
there is still a considerable degree of occupational segregation between
males and females—for example, nurses are much more likely to be females
and dentists males. But even after allowing for those factors, studies
have generally found that, on average, women earn roughly 10 percent less
than men even in comparable jobs, with equal levels of education,
training, and experience. Analysis of wage discrimination against black Americans leads to similar
conclusions. Specifically, after controlling for differences in age,
education, hours worked, experience, occupation, and region of the
country, wages for black men are roughly 10 percent lower than for white
men, though occupational segregation appears to be less common by race
than by gender. Issues other than wage discrimination are also important
to note for black workers. In particular, unemployment rates for black
workers are about twice as high as they are for white workers. Partly
because of that, a much lower percentage of the U.S. black population is
employed than the white population. Hispanic workers generally receive wages about 5 percent lower than white
workers, after adjusting for differences in education, training,
experience, and other characteristics that affect workers’ productivity.
Some studies suggest that differences in the ability to speak English are
particularly important in understanding wage differences for Hispanic
workers. The differences between the earnings of white males and earnings of
females and minorities slowly decreased in the closing decades of the
20th century. Some laws and regulations prohibiting discrimination seem
to have helped in this process. A large part of those gains occurred
shortly after the adoption of the 1964 Civil Rights Act, which among
other things, outlawed discrimination by employers and unions. Many
economists worry that the discrimination that remains may be more
difficult to identify and eliminate through legislation. Discrimination in competitive labor markets is economically inefficient
as well as unfair. When workers are not paid based on the value of what
they add to employers’ production and profit levels, society loses
opportunities to use labor resources in their most valuable ways. As a
result, fewer goods and services are produced. If employers discriminate
against certain groups of workers, they will pay for that behavior in
competitive markets by earning lower profits. Similarly, if workers
refuse to work with (or for) coworkers of a different gender, race, or
ethnic background, they will have to accept lower wages in competitive
markets because their discrimination makes it more costly for employers
to run their businesses. And if customers refuse to be served by workers
of a certain gender, race, or ethnicity in certain kinds of jobs, they
will have to pay higher prices in competitive markets because their
discrimination raises the costs of providing these goods and services. Those who are discriminated against receive lower wages and often
experience other forms of economic hardship, such as more frequent and
longer periods of unemployment. Beyond that, the lower wage rates and
restricted career opportunities they face will naturally affect their
decisions about how much education and training to acquire and what kinds
of careers to pursue. For that reason, some of the costs of
discrimination are paid over very long periods of time, sometimes for a
worker’s entire life. It is clear that there is still discrimination in the U.S. economy. What
is not always so clear is how much that discrimination costs the economy
as a whole, and that it costs not only those who are discriminated
against, but also those who practice discrimination. Unions Many U.S. workers belong to unions or to professional associations (such
as the National Education Association for teachers) that act like unions.
These unions and associations represent groups of workers in collective
bargaining with employers to agree on contracts. During this bargaining,
workers and employers establish wages and fringe benefits, such as health
care and pension benefits, for different types of jobs. They also set
grievance procedures to resolve labor disputes during the life of the
contract and often address many other issues, such as procedures for job
transfers and promotions of workers. Many studies indicate that wages for union workers in the United States
are 10 to 15 percent higher than for nonunion workers in similar jobs and
that fringe benefits for union workers also tend to be higher. That
compensation difference is an important consideration both for workers
thinking about joining unions, and for employers who are concerned about
paying higher wages and benefits than their competitors. In some cases,
it appears that the higher wages and benefits are paid because union
workers are more productive than nonunion workers are. But in other cases
unions have been found to decrease productivity, sometimes by limiting
the kinds of work that certain employees can do, or by requiring more
workers in some jobs than employers would otherwise hire. Economists have
not reached definite conclusions on some of these issues, but it is
evident that there are many other broad effects of unions on the economy.
Страницы: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14
|