The bulk of equity
investment has been into existing stocks in East Asian markets, driving up the
prices of equity. the cost of capital drops for those floating new issues, but
there are for also strong wealth effects on existing asset holders- as their
wealth increases, consumption is likely to go up as well. This will tend to
raise domestic prices and appreciate the currency in real terms, Whether these
foreign equity, investments increase physical investment depends on the
behavior of the other asset holders- those who sold to foreign investors and
those whose assets appreciated. If they invest in new projects, physical
investment will also increase, otherwise, it will not. It is more likely that
domestic savings will fall when there are large portfolio investment flows than
when the flows take the form of FDI. In Latin America, which has experienced
more portfolio inflows decline, rather than physical investment to increase. In
the past East Asia has avoided this result, partly because its overall policy
regime has favored investment, partly because of the greater degree of
sterilization it has been able to achieve, and partly because the share of portfolio
investment has been smaller. Portfolio flows are a very recent phenomenon, and
it is still to soon to measure many of their effects in East Asia.
It is particularly
worrisome when large private capital flows move into commercial real estate.
Experience in many countries, both industrial and developing, indicates the
ease with which speculative bubbles can develop in real estate during an
investment boom. Asset inflation in this sector can generate very high rates of
return- much higher than are available from investment in manufacturing- over a
few years. But such rates are not sustainable. When the bottom falls out, as it
inevitably does, there are frequently severe repercussions on the banking
sector, since domestic banks are usually major financiers of the real estate,
and governments often end up bailing out the financial sector. Indonesia faced
this problem in 1993; Thailand saw carliev bouts of these bubbles; and they are
not unknown in other countries, including the United States and Japan.
The sustainability of flows
into stock markets is a complex matter. To the extent that the flows depend on
continued high gains, mostly appreciation, one could wonder whether the high of
return of 1992-93 will resume after the 1994 correction. Even in the best of
circumstances, one would expect some flow reversals, in addition to normal
volatility. Unfortunately, the best of circumstances rarely occurs, and the
Mexican episode of December 1994 has precipitated outflows in many emerging
markets as fund managers have bailed out everywhere. It is hard not to view
this as herd behavior with a tinge of panic, but it caused a 3 percent
devaluation in Thailand and more than doubled short-term interest rates there.
Other East Asian markets have also suffered outflows as international investors
have generally reduced their exposure in emerging markets. However, giver the
long-term growth potential of the East Asian economies and the indications of a
longer-term stock adjustment process, there is reason to except that such
reactions will be temporary set backs in a persistent trend toward a lager
share of sound emerging market stocks in global portfolios. The spectacular
yields witnessed recently may not be sustainable, but the East Asian countries
should offer high rates of return over the long term and should continue to
attract investment.
A number of countries in
East Asia and elsewhere have begun attracting foreign portfolio investors into
their own fixed-income markets ,purchasing, instruments in local currency. In
this case the foreign bondholder takes the exchange risk, for which he expects
added compensation. It is encouraging that these economies are becoming
attractive enough, and their exchange management is considered stable enough,
to attract investment in local currency securities. For obvious reasons,
interest tends to be in bank deposits, in shorter maturities, and in guaranteed
instruments of government or their agencies.
To the extent that
short-term capital flows exceed working balances, trade financing, or bridge
activities to long-term investment, they are most likely the result of
relatively high interest rates not offset by an expected devolution. For the
most part, these flows are seeking high short-term rates of return and reflect
cash management or speculative decisions rather than long-term investment
decisions rather than long-term investment decisions. But like long-term flows,
they tend to lower domestic interest rates and appreciate the exchange rate.
They are likely to expand bank reserves and lead to more credit expansion,
although on a potentially more volatile base. To the extend that a government
is trying to restrain domestic demand with high interest rates, the inflow
would undermine its policy. These flows may not directly influence long-term
savings and investment, but they may do so.
The World Bank and
investment bankers regularly provide advice to developing countries on asset
and liability management. But that advice often is non optimal or simply wrong.
Although many tactical tools for active risk management in developing countries
have been developed in the past decade, a framework for developing a strategy
that incorporates country-specific factors has lagged far behind.
For example, in case when
the Federal Reserve Bank (the “Fed”) last September arranged a $3.6 billion
bailout of Long Term Capital Management (LTCM)- a Connecticut- based hedge
fund- critics of the US financial establishment cries foul. The bailout
contrasted strikingly with IMF treatment of indebted firms in Asia. When
indebted businesses in Asia were unable to replay foreign loads, US and IMF
officials insisted that they be forced to close and their assets sold off to
creditors. Bailing out ailing businesses with endless lines of bank credit was,
US officials claimed, the essence of “crony capitalism” and the cause of all
Asia’s problems “Reducing expectations of bailouts, ” declared the IMF, must be
step number one in restructuring Asia’s financial markets.
To Japanese officials, the
LTCM bailout was a clear case of the US “ignoring its own principles”.
Representative Bruce Vento (Democrat, Minnesota), in a Congressional
investigation of the LTCM bailout, said that “there seem to be two rules, a
double standard.” But this view is incorrect. Where bailouts are concerned,
there is only one standard. Whether in Korea, Thailand, Connecticut or Brazil,
US- and IMF- organized bailouts conform, to the same quiding principle:
whatever happens, whoever is at fault, the wealth of Western credits must be
protected and enhanced.
Until 1997, Western
creditors were bullish on Asia and “emerging markets” generally. They poured
billions into stocks, banks and businesses in Thailand, Indonesia, Korea,
expecting mega-returns and a piece of the action as the former “Third World” embraced
freemarket capitalism. Beginning in 1997, though, Western investors began to
worry that they might have over-lent. They pulled out of Thailand first,
selling baht for dollars; as the baht’s value collapsed, worry turned to panic.
Soon, international financial operators were selling won, ringgit, rupiah and
rubles in an effort to cut potential losses and get their funds safety back to
Europe and the US. In the ensuing capital flight, Asian stock prices plunged
and the value of Asian currencies collapsed. Local businesses that had taken
out dollar payments to Western creditors.
For a time, local
governments tries to stave off default by lending their reserves of foreign
currency to indebted firms. South Korea used up some $30 billion in this way.
But this money soon ran out. Western banks refused to make new loans or roll
over old debts. Asian businesses defaulted, cutting output and laying off
workers. As the economies worsened, panic intensified. Asian currencies lost 35
to 85 per cent of their foreign- exchange value, driving up prices on imported
goods and pushing down the standard of living. Businesses large and small were
driven to bankruptcy by the sudden drying up of credit; within a year, millions
of workers had lost jobs while prices of basic foodstuffs soared.
As the crisis unfolded, IMF
officials flew to Asia to arrange a bailout, agreeing ultimately to loan $120
billion to Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea. When announcing these loans,
the press used terms like “emergency assistance” and “international rescue
package,” leading the casual reader to presume that the money will be spent on
food for the hungry, or aid to the jobless. In float, the money is used to
“help” countries pay bank their debts to international banks and brokerage houses.
Which international banks and brokerage house? The same ones who made
speculative loans in the first place, then panicked and brought about the
collapse of the Asian economies. The IMF rescue packages are intended only to
rescue the Western creditors.
The Western financial
industry, moreover, has been lobbying heavily for even more secure protection
from future losses. One plan, put forward last year by the US and US
Treasuries, envisions a $90 billion fund of public money, supposedly to avert
currency crises. The idea is that G7 governments will, henceforth, underwrite
the finance industry’s speculative ventures into emerging, markets before,
rather than after, they turn sour. In this way, when bankers and fund mangers
grow bored with a particular market, withdraw their funds and send the currency
into a tailspin, they can collect on their losses immediately, without the
tedious and time- consuming delays generated by IMF negotiations.
The industry has also been
working overtime to squelch defensive government action against their
speculative attacks. At a recent conference in New York City, economist Jagdish
Bhagwati noted that the IMF and the US Government, despite repeated crises and
heavy criticism have intensities pressures on countries to lift exchange
controls. The IMF recently proposed changing its Articles of Agreement so as to
require countries to permit even more freedom for financial speculations.
Echoing this sentiment, US Treasury official Lawrence Summers decried efforts
by Malaysia, Hong Kong and other to curb foreign lending, calling capital
controls “a catastrophe” and urging countries to “open up to foreign financial
service” providers, and all the competition, capital and expertise they bring
with them.
Critics of IMF and US
policy have, of course, noted that the combination of free flowing capital and
bailout funds are a boon to banks other creditors. Such IMF critics as
financier George Soros and Harvard’s Jeffrey Sachs complain that the game of
international speculation and bailout played by the Western financial
establishment- in which hot money rushes into a country, then pulls out,
leaving behind a wrecked economy to be cleaned up by local governments and G7
taxpayers- is a menace to world economic stability. For the Western financial
establishment, however, the bailouts are not the real prize. Nor are the
devastated economies of Asia an unfortunate side-effect of a financial scamp.
They are the while point of the game. Asia’s bankrupt businesses, insolvent
banks and jobless millions are the spoils of what economist Michel Chossudovsky
aptly calls “financial warfare”. The gains to be won from these financial
hit-and-runs are immense. There are, first of all, the foreign- exchange
reserves of the target countries. Countries accumulate currency reserves by
running trade surpluses, often after year upon year of selling more abroad than
they purchase. These surpluses are accumulated at great cost to the working
populations, who labor hard to produce goods, destined to be consumed by foreigners.
In 1997-1998, Asian countries spent nearly $100 billion in accumulated
reserves trying- vainly as it turned out- to prevent devaluation. Brazil, the
latest country to fall, spent $36 billion defending the real against
speculators. Thus, in little over a year, did the Western financial elite
confiscate $136 billion of hard-won wealth from the emerging markets.
Next, there are the
bargains to be had once the target country’s currency has collapsed and its
firms are strapped for cash. Year of effort, for example, by the Korean elite
to keep businesses firmly under control of state-supported conglomerates called
chaebols were undone in a matter of months. By early 1998, as the IMF
negotiated the terms of surrender, Citigroup, Goldman Sachs and other firms
were snatching up ownership of Asian banks and industries. With currencies down
15-60 per cent and stock prices down 40-60 per cent, Asia is today a bargain-
hunter’s paradise. Nor are assets the only bargains to be had. As a direct
result of the destruction wrought by global financial interests, the prices of
basic commodities have plummeted over the past year. Oil. Copper, steel,
lumber, paper pulp, pork, coffee, rice can now be bought up by Western firms
dirt cheap, an important key to the continued profitability of US industry.
Then there is the higher
tribune that countries, once in debt peonage to Western creditors, must pay on
both old and new loans. South Korea, for example, under the terms of the IMF
bailout, will pay interest on foreign loans that is 25-30 per cent higher that
rates on comparable international loans- this despite the fact that the loans
have been guaranteed by the Korean Government. Since the crisis began,
international lenders have doubled or tripled the interest rates they charge on
emerging- market debt. What is such usurious interest cripples the economy and
drives the country into default? Well ,then they will become wards of the IMF,
lender of last resort.
Next, there are the people
themselves, engulfed in debt, impoverished and committed by their governments
to can endless course of domestic austerity and debt crisis of the 1980s, the
Asian crisis has resulted in millions of newly unemployed, whose desperation
will pull wages down world-wide. Like the debt crisis of the 1980s, the Asian
crisis will turn entire countries into export platforms, where human labor is
transformed into the foreign exchange needed to repay Asia’s $600 billion debt.
In just this past year, Thai rice exports rose by 75 per cent, while Korea has
managed to boost its exports and accumulate $41 billion in reserves for debt
service. These figures, notes the World Bank, indicate that people in Asia “are
working harder and eating less”.
Finally there are the
governments themselves, the ultimate prizes to be won. It is no accident that
conditions imposed by the IMF, with their emphasis on altering state
employment, welfare and pension systems, their insistence on reforming the
legal and political systems of the target countries, entail a major loss of national
sovereignty. Through IMF negotiations, national governments are transformed
into local enforcement agents of transnational corporations and banks. IMF
officials are quick to point out that the usurped governments often were not
paragons of democracy and virtue. This of course is true. But the motives of
the IMF are themselves profoundly undemocratic, intended to seize sovereignty
and fix the rules of the game and to protect and expand, at all cost the wealth
of the international financial elite.
|